In this article we will discuss about the equilibrium of a firm under monopolistic competition. Assumptions of Equilibrium Analysis of a Firm:

The equilibrium analysis of a firm under monopolistic competition is based on the following assumptions that are peculiar to monopolistic competition.

(i) The firms here produce products of the product-group, each producing one particular product.

(ii) They share the total market for the product-group equally.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

(iii) They are equal in respect of cost of production and also in respect of their reactions to changes in different parameters.

Apart from the above assumptions, there would also be present in our analysis the usual assumptions such as those of the profit-maximising goal of the firms and of the third degree and second degree shapes of the total, average and marginal cost curves.

Equilibrium of the Firm in the Short Run:

We shall explain the short-run equilibrium of an individual firm under monopolistic competi­tion with the help of Fig. 13.1, where SAC and SMC are the short-run average and marginal cost curves of the firm. On the demand side, if there are n firms, each firm would be able to sell, by assumption, 1/nth part of the market demand for the product-group at any particular price.

This is shown by what is known as the proportional demand (PD) curve. This curve is given by the curve PD in Fig. 13.1.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Now, given the PD curve, let us start from a short-run disequilibrium position where the price is p0. At p = p0, the firm would be able to sell the output q = q0, which is the amount of proportional demand, i.e., which is equal to 1/nth part of the total demand for the product-group at the said price.

However, according to the perception of the firm, if the price of its product decreases from p = p0, the prices of all other products of the group remaining unchanged, then the quantity demanded of its product (q) would increase more than that along the PD curve—it would increase along a flatter demand curve like AR.

This curve is known as the firm’s ‘perceived’ demand or AR curve. All the ‘perceived’ AR and MR curves have been drawn as straight lines in Fig. 13.1, for the sake of simplicity. The marginal curve of AR1 is MR1.

The firm thinks that it would be able to maxim­ise profit at the MR = MC point which is the point L1 in this case. At L1, the profit-maximising price-output combi­nation is (p1, q1) which is obtained at the point K1 on the AR1 line.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Now, as the firm sets p = p1, it would be able to sell not q = q1 > PD, but q = p1T1 = PD, T1 being a point on its PD curve. This would be so, because, as the firm decreases the price from p0 to p1, all other firms react in the same way, by assumption, i.e., all other firms also would reduce the prices of their products to p = p1.

It follows then that, at p = p1, when the firm sells q = p1T1 and not q = q1, it would not be able to maximise profit. Therefore, the firm would again want to move along its ‘perceived’ demand curve, which is now obtained to be the line AR2. The marginal curve for AR2 is the line MR2. The MR = MC point, now, is Land the corresponding profit-maximising price-output combination is K2(p2, q2) on the ARline.

However, as before, the firm’s goal of profit-maximisation would not be achieved at p = p2, because, all other firms would charge now the same price and each firm (and our firm also) would now be able to sell not q = q2 > PD, but q = p2T2 = PD, where T2 is a point on the PD curve.

Since, at the point T2, the firm is still in a disequilibrium position, it would now try again to achieve its profit-maximising goal, and the process would go on.

It is now clear, from the above analysis that the firm would be moving from one ‘perceived’ equilibrium to another along a path shown by the dotted line passing through K1, K2, etc. in Fig, 13.1 till its ‘perceived’ equilibrium combination, while moving along the said dotted line, reaches the PD curve at a point like Ke(pe, qe).

Now, every point on the dotted line lies on some ‘perceived’ AR curve and, for this point, we also have MR = MC.

Therefore, Ke must be a point on some AR line which is, let us suppose ARe, and for the point Ke or at q = qe, we have MR = MC at the point Le. Ke(pe, qe), therefore, is a ‘perceived’ profit-maxim­ising (p, q) combination at which the firm would be willing to sell q = qe at p = pe.

However, since the point Ke lies on the PD curve, the firm would be able to sell actually q = qe at p = pe. That is, Ke (pe, qe) would be the ‘perceived’ profit-maximising price-output combination where the goal would be realised also. In other words, the firm is in short-run equilibrium at the MR = MC point Le and its equilibrium (p, q) combination is Ke(pe, qe).

It is seen in Fig. 13.1 that at this equilibrium point the firm’s AR = Keqe is greater than its AC = Neqe which gives us that in this short-run equilibrium, the firm would be able to earn more than normal profit. The amount of excess profit here is equal to □peKeNeH.

Short-Run Equilibrium of a Firm